11 Growth and Equity in IndianAgriculture and a Few Paradigmsfrom Bangladesh
This is the html version of the file http://www.ifpri.org/pubs/books/Mellor85/Mellor85ch11.pdf.
G o o g l e automatically generates html versions of documents as we crawl the web.
To link to or bookmark this page, use the following url: http://www.google.com/u/Oxford?q=cache:K7Zv_u2zgJIJ:www.ifpri.org/pubs/books/Mellor85/Mellor85ch11.pdf+land+holdings+redistribution+india&hl=en&ct=clnk&cd=191&ie=UTF-8
Google is neither affiliated with the authors of this page nor responsible for its content.
These search terms have been highlighted: land redistribution india
These terms only appear in links pointing to this page: holdings
Page 1
11 Growth and Equity in IndianAgriculture
and a Few Paradigmsfrom Bangladesh
RAISUDDIN AHMED
In chapter 10 of this volume, M. L. Dantwala presents an excellent
overview of growth-with-equity issues in Indian agriculture. Although he
does not attempt to define the problem of measuring inequality and
absolute poverty, his arguments imply that absolute poverty is the most
urgent concern of Indian policy makers.
1
Since my disagreements with
Dantwala are few, I shall attempt primarily to amplify and supplement
some of his points on institutional policies and present some paradigms
from Bangladesh.
Institutional Policies
Dantwala asks whether the emphasis on the new seed-cum-fertilizer
technology has resulted in the neglect of institutional changes and tilted
the balance of social justice against the poor. Development of market
institutions, particularly those related to new technology, has been
impressive. Credit and marketing cooperatives, special programs for
small and marginal farmers, intensive agriculturaldevelopment in selected
districts, and special employment programs for rural laborersare someof
the institutional arrangements that have fewparallels in otherlow-income
market economies. Some studies indicate that in recent years about 33
percent of the institutional credit was shared by small farms holding less
than 2 hectares, which had only about 25 percent of the total cultivated
area (as reviewed in Sarma 1981). The interest rate was reduced 10-15
percent in the informal credit markets of the Punjab and Haryana by
innovative credit institutions and new technology. Although most of
these institutions did not reach their goals, their achievements are by no
means inconsequential.
The new market institutions contributed only marginally to alleviating
poverty because they contributed littleto the income ofthose whohad no
access to land. Egalitarian distribution of land not only redistributes
124
Page 2
Growth and Equityin Indian Agriculture 125
access to productive assets but also broadens the power structureinrural
areas, so that benefitsfrom other policies are spread more evenlyamong
rural people. Dantwala hasindicated that the distribution ofland maybe
less unequal than it appears if differences inqualityof land are considered.
But even if these differences and thosecaused bythe positive correlation
between farm sizeand family sizeare allowed, the inequalitycouldstill be
large.
2
The setting of land ownershipceilings in India has inpracticeprovided
little land for distribution. Even with a lower ceiling (say, 4-12 hectares,
depending on the state), the supply of surplus land for redistribution to
small and landless households is adequate only in the northwestern
states, where other employmentopportunities are available. In the eastern
and most southern states, where landlessness and absolute poverty are
widespread, there is not enough land to redistribute even with a low
ceiling (Singh 1982).
Bangladesh Paradigms
Because of similarities in regional resource endowment, population
density, and production patterns, the experience ofBangladeshhasmuch
in common with that of India, particularly eastern India.
A little more than 90percent of the population of Bangladesh livesin
rural areas. Most have few assets of any kind. A large proportion of
cultivators are small and marginal. About 50percent ofthe farms are less
than 2.5 acres, 19percent of the cultivated areas beingunder some form
of tenancy. These small and marginalfarms buy muchof theirfoodgrain
supply from the market (Ahmed 1981). They supplement income from
their farm by earnings from petty trades, services, and labor, which
themselves are closely related to agriculture. The AgriculturalCensusof
1977 indicates that the proportion of rural households not operating any
land and depending primarily on wages from work as hired agricultural
laborers ranges from 23percent in Tangail to 34percent inRangpur.The
country average is29percent. If economic progress isasslowinthe future
as in the past, and if the population continues to grow,even ifat aslower
rate, the proportion of landless households in rural areas will double by
the year 2000.
The behavior of wage rates and employmentof unskilled agricultural
labor in the wake ofagricultural growth isone ofthe most important links
between poverty and agricultural growth.The average index of the real
agricultural wage rate fell from 97in the first half of the 1960s to 51in the
first half of the 1970s and 72 in the second half. The choice of different
years would still lead to the same conclusion. Apparently, failureof the
money wage rate to keep pace with the prices of commodities generally
Page 3
126 Raisuddin Ahmed
consumed by laborers resulted in this decline. But a primarycause of the
decline in real wages was the failure of agricultural productivity to keep
pace with the growth of the labor force. Econometric analysis shows
significant and positive relationships between real wage rates of agri-
cultural labor and agricultural production. However, the growth rate of
agricultural production hasto be higher than the growth ratein population
to affect real wage rates perceptibly. If the aggregate demand for labor
does not grow as much asfamily labor supply, then the demand for hired
labor tends to stagnate or fall, and so does the real wage rate (Ahmed
1981). Between 1960 and 1980, agricultural production grew byabout 1.8
percent annually, and the population grew by2.6percent. Some estimates
indicate that agricultural employment grew byonly 1.2percent.
3
High-yield varieties have covered no more than 18percent of the area
sown with rice. Although high-yield varieties are 50-60 percent more
labor-intensive, the resulting increase in employment has been sub-
stantially offset by a reduction in the area sown with jute, which also is
labor-intensive. Rural trade, services, and industries, which provide
some employment for the rural poor, indirectly depend on agricultural
production. Therefore, the growth in employment in these pursuitsmay
not have been much different from that in agriculture. This implies that
stagnation in agriculture, high population growth, and the increasing
proportion of landless households in rural areas caused rural poverty to
increase.
Redistribution of land has often been suggested as a prerequisite for
fast agricultural growth that includes the poor. The immediate question
in Bangladesh iswhether enough surplus land isavailable fordistribution.
Eleven percent of rural households in Bangladesh did not own any
homestead land in 1977, 22 percent owned land only to accommodate
homesteads, and 38 percent cultivated less than 2.5 acres per household
(Government of Bangladesh, Bureau of Statistics 1979). Assume that a
six-person household owning 3.0 acres of land is a subsistence unit
4
and
also the ceiling for land ownership. This ceilingwouldresult inabout 4.44
million acres of surplus land. This would only be enough to provide
homestead land to landless households and to raise the size ofmarginal
farms to 0.5 acre per capita. Even if it were politically possible, there is
not enough land in Bangladesh to organize farming into viableunitsand
provide land to all landless and small, submarginal farm households for
long.
Although labor-intensive nonagricultural development isemphasized
as a long-run solution to the problems of Bangladesh, agricultural
development will be crucialduringthe comingdecade. Production canbe
doubled with known technology. Presently, only about 12percent of the
cultivated area has a controlled supply of irrigationwater; no more than
Page 4
Growth and Equity in Indian Agriculture 127
20 percent of the area under rice is sown with high-yield-varietyseeds;
and only about 40 percent of crop area is fertilized at two-thirdsof the
recommended amounts.
Until 1973/74, about 80percent of government allocations for irrigation
went to large-scale projects, which covered only about 10percent of the
area irrigated under all projects (Ahmed 1977). In recent years larger
shares of public resources have gone to small-scale irrigation, but a big
push to develop irrigation primarily through small-scale tubewellsisyet
to come. Technical studies indicate that enough groundwaterisavailable
(World Bank 1972). Incentives involving a large number of farmers
would be a key factor in the success of such a strategy. Formation oflocal
institutions to organize farm groups to operate tube wells would be a
second important element.
The new agricultural technology and tube-well irrigation do not dis-
criminate against small farmers as much as has been suggested (Gauhar
1982). Independent studies by the Bangladesh Institute of Development
Studies show that much of the criticism is baseless (BIDS 1980). The
proportion of total irrigated land operated by the small farmers under
these projects is no less than the proportion of total land operated by
small farmers. No evidence was found in the project area of anyunusual
transfers of land. Nevertheless, withthe new emphasison private initiative
in small-scale irrigation, large farmersprobably wouldbenefit morethan
small farmers. But increases in the demand for labor and in the
expenditures ofwell-to-dofarmerson consumergoodswouldoffset some
of these negative consequences.
Notes
1. This concern is expressed explicitly in Government of India, Planning
Commission (1973).
2. The Indian National Sample Survey (26th Round) indicatesthat in 1970/71,
75 percent of Indian farmers were classified as small and marginal, owning only
about 25 percent of the total cultivated land. On the other hand, only about 2
percent of the large-farm households owned about 23 percent of the land. The
trend was a slight increase in the proportion of small and marginal farms with a
decreasing share of land.
3. This includes family labor. The employment of wage labor must have
increased at a slower rate because aggregate demand increased at a slower rate
than did the growth infamilylabor. For growthin aggregateemployment see Clay
and Khan (1977).
4. The average farm size in Bangladesh is about 3.5 acres. Calculations based
on farm income, costs, and living expenses indicate a subsistence unit ofabout 3.0
acres for a family of six, at the current level of technology. Technological change
would change this subsistence threshold, aswould population growth.
No comments:
Post a Comment